General

Large Cities in USA less Green than Small Ones

Large cities emit more CO2 and earn no more per capita than small cities, contradicting the ‘economy of scale’ that makes larger cities ‘greener’ than small ones and raising doubt over claims of other benefits.

by Dr Mae-Wan Ho

Allometric scaling relationships in biology applied to cities

Allometric scaling relationships were first discovered in biology in the relative dimensions of parts of the body, as for example brain size and body size in the course of development and evolution [1]. It was later applied to metabolic rate of animals Y relative to body mass X [2] in the general form:

Y = AXb (1)

…where A is a constant and b = ¾ the allometric exponent. A plot of log Y against log X gives the slope b and the intercept on the Y axis log A. The amazing thing is that it applies across kingdoms of the entire living world, from mouse to elephant (see Figure 1 from [3] Biology’s Theory of Everything, SiS 21 ) and even from bacteria to whales and giant redwood trees [4].


Figure 1 Allometric scaling of metabolic rate with body weight from mouse to elephant [3]

Recently, allometric scaling has been used to study cities, especially by theoretical physicists Geoffrey West and Luis Bettencourt at Santa Fe Institute in the United States [5, 6]. They found that cities across the US show allometric relations with population size. In particular, human activities can be grouped into 3 categories according to the value of the allometric exponent: isometric (b= 1) reflects individual human needs: number of jobs, houses, water consumption; sublinear (b < 1) implies an economy of scale with per capita measurement decreasing with population size, as in the number of gasoline stations, length of electrical cables, road surfaces, even greenhouse gas emissions; and superlinear (b > 1) implying positive per capita gain with population size in variables such as wages, income, gross domestic product, bank deposits and rates of invention (patents). Sublinear scaling indicates savings on infrastructure, while superlinear scaling indicates that larger cities are associated with increased levels of human productivity and quality of life (see [7] "Grand Unified Theory of Sustainability" for Cities? SiS 64) .

Are bigger cities really greener as well as richer and more creative?

There has been intense debate over whether large cities are greener (reviewed in [8]). Some studies report that commuting makes a major contribution to greenhouse gas emissions. Consequently, compact cities would be greener by reducing the average commuting distance; but this has been hotly disputed, at least in the US on ground that a compact city would drive people to live outside the city and lengthen the commuting distance instead.

Erneson Oliveria, José Andrade Jr at Federal University of Ceara, Brazil, and Hernán Makse at City College of New York in the United States carried out a new study to see if larger cities are greener than smaller ones [8]. They used a new bottom-up approach combining two datasets on population and carbon dioxide emissions in continental USA, both the most finely detailed available. What they found was devastating: a superlinear scaling between CO2 emissions and city population, with average allometric exponent b =
1.46 across all cities in the US. In other words, doubling the size of cities leads to an increase of 146 % in CO2 emissions instead of 100%. They concluded: “This result suggests that the high productivity of large cities is done at the expense of a proportionally larger amount of emissions compared to small cities.”

Detailed databases combined with good clustering algorithm to identify cities

Why are the new findings so different? And why should we have more confidence in their results rather than those obtained previously by others?

First, the new findings are based on the most detailed databases for population and carbon emissions available, and second, a robust algorithm is used to identify cities, rather than relying on administrative definitions that often arbitrarily lump suburban and other outlying areas into cities.

The team started by aggregating settlements that are close to each other into cities using the City Clustering Algorithm (CCA). Then, they use the data of CO2 emissions at a fine geographic scale to determine the total emissions of each city.

Their results are substantially different from those obtained by the standard administrative definition of cities, i.e., Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA), which display isometric scaling emissions or even sublinear scaling. This suggests that allometric studies based on administrative boundaries to define cities may suffer from inherent bias.

The carbon emission dataset is obtained from the Vulcan Project compiled at Arizona State University, and has a spatial resolution of 10 x 10 km (0.1deg x 0.1 deg grid) from 1999 to 2009. The data are separated according to economic sectors and activities: commercial, industrial and residential, electricity production, on-road vehicles, non-road vehicles (boats, trains, snow mobiles), aircraft, and cement.

The team analysed the annual average emissions in 2002 for total of all sectors combined and each sector separately. The choice of 2002 data is because that is the only year for which the quantification has been achieved at the scale of individual factories, power plants, roadways and neighbourhoods, and on an hourly basis.

The CCA considers cities as constituted of contiguous commercial and residential areas (at cut-off distance l = 5km and population threshold D* = 1 000) for which the emissions of CO2
are known from the Vulcan Project dataset. By using two microscopically defined datasets, the team could match precisely the population of each agglomeration to its rate of CO2 emission.

For l = 5 km and D* = 1 000, the plot of log (CO2) vs log (Pop) gives log A = -2.05 + 0.12 and b = 1.38 + 0.03, with R2 = 0.76. R is the correlation coefficient and the value of R2 is the proportion of the variation in CO2 that can be accounted for by the linear part of its relation with Pop (population); hence the closer it is to 1 for a positive slope, the better the fit to the model (Figure 2).


Figure 2: Scaling of CO2 emission versus population. Solid red line the linear regression, grey circles
the data points, solid black line the Nadaraya-Watson estimate of the unknown regression function
(with dashed black lines the 95 % confidence interval of the estimate), dotted blue line is that of a
theoretical regression with b = 1

How robust is the allometric exponent to the thresholds D* and l? Does it depend critically on the precise thresholds chosen? This was investigated by varying the values of the thresholds of l and D*and seeing how the allometric exponent b changes. The value of b was found to increase with l until a saturation value is reached at 10 km, which is relatively independent of D*. An average of the exponent values in the plateau region with l > 10 km over different D* gives b = 1.46 + 0.02. The CO2 emissions of each sector was also plotted separately to obtain the allometric exponents. The sectors with highest exponents (less efficient) are residential, industrial, commercial and electric production with b ranging from 1.46
to 1.62, above the average.

Income scales superlinearly with carbon emissions except for the lowest levels

The team also made use of the US income dataset available from the US Census Bureau for the year 2000. The dataset provides the mean household income per capita for the 3 092 US counties. For each county, they
combined the income data and the administrative boundaries in order to relate them with the geolocated datasets.

The allometric exponent of income per capita shows an inverted U-shape dependence on total income. In other words, the allometric exponent b decreases for the lower and higher income levels. The
turning point is per capita income of $37 235 (in 2000 US dollars). The allometric exponent remains always larger than 1 (superlinear) regardless of income level, except for the lowest income.

When CO2 emissions are plotted separately for different income levels, there is a superlinear relation for all levels (b ranging from 1.23 at the highest income level to 1.43 at an intermediate level) except for the lowest < $25 119 (b  = 0.92).  After the turning point, b decreases indicating an environmental improvement in largest income cities. However, the allometric exponent remains larger than one throughout except for the lowest income level, indicating that almost all large cities are less green than small ones, no matter their income.

Comparison with allometric relations for area obtained for cities identified by MSA with cities identified by CCA shows that the MSA plot overestimates the area of cities, especially small cities. The MSA plot gives log AMSA = 0.81 +0.36 and bMSA = 0.51 + 0.06 (R2= 0.48). The CCA plot gives log ACCA = -2.86 +0.06 and bCCA = 0.94 + 0.01 (R2= 0.99). Hence the fit to the model based on CCA is much better than that based on MSA. There is nearly isometric scaling between population and area for CCA while the MSA plot shows a sublinear scaling. The CCA isometric relationship shows that the emission is independent of the population density, as expected, but leads to a superlinear scaling between emissions and population size. The MSA overestimates occupied area typically, and the bias is larger for small cities than larger ones; consequently, an overestimation of the CO2 emission of the small cities compared to larger cities. That accounts for a smaller allometric exponent for MSA than CCA for the plot of log (CO2) versus log (Pop), which give log AMSA = 1.08 + 0.38 and bMSA = 0.92 + 0.07 (R2 = 0.71).

The paper has omitted to plot income against city size, which would give a direct comparison with results obtained previously [5, 6]. At my request, the authors kindly provided such a plot of log income per capita versus log population (not shown).

The scaling exponent b = 0.017+ 0.006, with R2 = 0.014. In other words, there is very weak positive correlation between income and city size. That means per capita income is practically unchanged, or increases only slightly with city size; again at odds with the superlinear scaling found previously [4-6].

The new results show convincingly that larger cities are less green than smaller cities, and cast considerable doubt over previous analyses based on MSA cities, for which many other positive benefits have been claimed.

In my Prigogine Medal 2014 Inaugural Lecture for Sustainable City 2014 at University of Siena, 23 September 2014, I shall show how cities can become sustainable like organisms (for further details see: https://www.wessex.ac.uk/14-conferences/sustainable-city-2014.html).

References

  1. Huxley JS and Tessier G. Terminology of relative growth Nature 1936, 137, 780-1.
  2. Kleiber M. The fire of life: An introduction to animal energetic, John Wiley, New York, 1961.
  3. Ho MW. Biology’s theory of everything? Science in Society 21, 47, 2014.
  4. West GB, Brown JH and Enquist BJ. A general model for the origin of allometric scaling laws in biology. Science 1997, 276, 122-6.
  5. Bettencourt LMA, Lobo J, Helbing D, Kühnert C and West GB. Growth, innovation, scaling, and the pace of life in cities. PNAS 2007, 104, 7301-6.
  6. Bettencourt LMA. The origins of scaling in cities. Science 2013, 340, 1438-41.
  7. Ho MW. “Grand Unified Theory of Sustainability” for cities? Science in Society 64 (to appear) 2014.
  8. Oliveria EA, Andrade Jr JS, Makse HA. Large cities are less green. arXiv:1401.7720v2, 18 June 2014. https://arxiv.org/abs/1401.7720

One Comment

  1. Hello Dr Mae-Wan Ho,

    This is excellent analysis. I am doing my PhD on assessment of urban carrying capacity. I will definitely use your paper/article in my work.

    Also, thanks for writing this article. I just downloaded source 8 you cited. It is indeed very interesting. Many believe that compact cities are more sustainable. It is not the population density rather size of the city that matter. Large cities can never be sustainable.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Related Articles

Back to top button